It's Friday. Let's Philosophize!
Friday, March 28, 2014
Friday, March 21, 2014
RECASP
I'm not sure how regular publication of this journal is going to be, or even if it is going to be anything other an an online project, but the University of Wollongong in Australia has a link to the Review of Capital as Power.
There's a list of articles here and you can download the individual pdfs. I note only that Volume 1, Issue 1 for 2012 had only one article and that Volume 1, Issue 1 for 2013 has carried over to 2014. It is clearly a work in (slow) progress.
Thursday, March 13, 2014
Interstitial Emergence
Human
beings are social, not societal
A theoretical assumption lies at the
base of the unitary conception: Because people are social animals, they have a
need to create a society, a bounded and patterned social totality. But this is
false. Human beings need to enter into social power relations, but they do not need
social totalities. They are social, but not societal, animals.
Let us consider some of their needs
again. As they desire sexual fulfillment, they seek sexual relations, usually
with only a few members of the opposite sex; as they desire to reproduce themselves,
these sexual relations usually combine with relations between adults and children.
For these (and other purposes), a family emerges, enjoying patterned
interaction with other family units from which sexual partners might be found.
As humans need material subsistence, they develop economic relationships,
cooperating in production and exchange with others. There is no necessity that
these economic networks be identical to family or sexual networks, and in most cases,
they are not. As humans explore the ultimate meaning of the universe, they
discuss beliefs and perhaps participate with others similarly inclined in
rituals and worship in a church. As humans defend whatever they have obtained,
and as they pillage others, they form armed bands, probably of younger men, and
they require relations with nonfighters who feed and equip them. As humans
settle disputes without constant recourse to force, they set up judicial
organizations with a specified area of competence. Where is the necessity for
all these social requirements to generate identical sociospatial interaction
networks and form a unitary society?
Tendencies toward forming a singular
network derive from the emergent need to institutionalize social relations.
Questions of economic production, of meaning, of armed defense, and of judicial
settlement are not fully independent of one another. The character of each is
likely to be influenced by the character of all, and all are necessary for
each. A given set of production relations will require common ideological and
normative understandings, and it will require defense and judicial regulation.
The more institutionalized these interrelations, the more the various power
networks converge toward one unitary society.
But we must recall the original dynamic.
The driving force of human society is not institutionalization. History derives
from restless drives that generate various networks of extensive and intensive
power relations. These networks have a more direct relation to goal attainment
than institutionalization has. In pursuit of their goals, humans further
develop these networks, outrunning the existing level of institutionalization.
This may happen as a direct challenge to existing institutions, or it may
happen unintentionally and “interstitially” – between their interstices and
around their edges – creating new relations and institutions that have
unanticipated consequences for the old.
This is reinforced by the most permanent
feature of institutionalization, the division of labor. Those involved in
economic subsistence, ideology, military defense and aggression, and political
regulation possess a degree of autonomous control over their means of power
that then further develops relatively autonomously. Marx saw that the forces of
economic production continuously outdistance institutionalized class relations and
throw up emergent social classes. The model was extended by writers like Pareto
and Mosca: The power of “elites” could also rest on noneconomic
power resources. Mosca summarized the result:
If a new source of wealth develops in a society, if the practical importance of knowledge grows, if an old religion declines or a new one is born, if a new current of ideas spreads, then, simultaneously, far-reaching dislocations occur in the ruling class. One might say, indeed, that the whole history of civilised mankind comes down to a conflict between the tendency of dominant elements to monopolise political power and transmit possession of it by inheritance and the tendency toward a dislocation of old forces and an insurgence of new forces; and this conflict produces an unending ferment of endosmosis and exosmosis between the upper classes and certain portions of the lower.
Mosca's model, like Marx's, ostensibly
shares the unitary view of society: Elites rise and fall within the same social
space. But when Marx actually described the rise of the bourgeoisie (his
paradigm case of a revolution in the forces of production), it was not like
that. The bourgeoisie rose “interstitially”; it emerged between the “pores” of
feudal society, he said. The bourgeoisie, centered on the towns, linked up with
landowners, tenant farmers, and rich peasants, treating their economic
resources as commodities to create new networks of economic interaction,
capitalist ones. Actually, as we see in Chapters 14 and 15, it helped create
two different overlapping networks, one bounded by the territory of the
medium-sized state and one much more extensive, labeled by Wallerstein (1974)
the “world system.” The bourgeois revolution did not change the character of an
existing society; it created new societies.
I term such processes interstitial emergence. They are the
outcome of the translation of human goals into organizational means. Societies
have never been sufficiently institutionalized to prevent interstitial
emergence. Human beings do not create unitary societies but a diversity of
intersecting networks of social interaction. The most important of these
networks form relatively stably around the four power sources in any given
social space. But underneath, human beings are tunneling ahead to achieve their
goals, forming new networks, extending old ones, and emerging most clearly into
our view with rival configurations of one or more of the principal power
networks.
Michael Mann, The Sources of Social Power: Volume 1, A
History of Power from the Beginning to AD 1760, pp. 14-16.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)