Tuesday, May 27, 2008

Primavera Band Profile 2008 #4

Throbbing Gristle
"Part Two: Endless Not" (Mute, 2007)
Greatest exponents of the industrial machinery that at the end of the sixties lubricated rock with insane doses of aggressiveness, experimentation and post modern nightmares, Throbbin Gristle come back to life to regain their condition of conventionalism lashers and to continue shaping this sonic terrorism they engraved with fire in their unpredictable live shows. The British band dismembered in 1981, got back together in 2004 to offer in London their first concert in more than two decades. The come back, endorsed by their concert in All Tomorrow’s Parties 2005, was materialized last year in "Part Two: Endless Not", first album of the band in 25 years and the excuse for bringing Genesis P. Orridge and company back to the stages. One must remember the performance of the androgynous and amoral Orridge leading Psychic TV in Estrella Damm Primavera Sound 2005 to get an idea of what will probably happen in Throbbing Gristle’s come back.

Friday, May 23, 2008

It's Friday. Let's Boogie!

France's Eurovision entry. Sebastien Tellier: "Divine."

Wednesday, May 21, 2008

Two Sevens Clash

Thanks to Reidski for the tag

List seven songs you are into right now. No matter what the genre, whether they have words, or even if they’re not any good, but they must be songs you’re really enjoying now, shaping your spring. Post these instructions in your blog along with your 7 songs. Then tag 7 other people to see what they’re listening to.

By and large new stuff bought on CD, most of which can be heard on Marc Riley's Brain Surgery where I find my musical inspiration these days. I've still got two Scout Niblett CDs and the new Tindersticks to listen to yet, so this'll probably be redundant tomorrow.



"Nevada" - Scout Niblett. I've known about Scout for a fair few years without ever hearing her material. The Guardian linked to a video she did with Will Oldham recently and now I can't get enough. Saw her live in Manchester this week and was gobsmacked

"Atomsmashers" - Chris Mills. Off his new album, Living in the Aftermath, but he's been playing it live for over a year.

"The Devil's Crayon" - Wild Beasts. New single, not as weird as the earlier singles, which is a shame.

"Weather to Fly" - Elbow. Again a band that's been around a while but I've just started to get into.

"Cross Your Fingers" - Laura Marling. If she keeps this up she could be huge.

"What Is Not But Could Be If" - Silver Jews. Marc Riley has been playing this alot. Looking forward to seeing it performed live next week.

"But I Did Not" - Howe Gelb. Off the Sno'Angel LP. Unfortunately, he didn't have the gospel choir with him in Manchester last week.

And the shout goes out to Griff, Pep, Jordi, Cakes (both), Stef and, erm, Prenderghast.

Fruit U Like

The May/June issue of Orion magazine carries an excerpt from The Fruit Hunters in which author Adam Leith Gollner explains how marketers promote fruit:

. . . Branding gurus want to make fruits a part of transitions from one activity to the next: rejuvenating tide-me-over breaks, midafternoon pickmeups, and after-work snacks. To merchandising reps, it doesn't really matter when these moments happen as long as they become ritualized routines filled with fruit. Once fruits have become ingrained as the go-to transitionary fuel, their multisensory experiential qualities can be leveraged into high-volume snacking. Or something to that effect.

Fruit catchphrases and slogans bandied about in these studies include "little taste adventure," "delicious handful of goodness," and my favorite: "the snack that quenches."


Pass the fags, Alice.

Quasi-State Actors . . .

. . . or relatively unsuccessful gangsters? Patrick J. Garrity has an article in the latest issue of the journal Comparative Strategy on the U.S. government's battle against Barbary pirates in the 19th century. It's reviewed here in the Wilson Quaterly.

The war on terror isn’t America’s first battle against an amorphous Muslim “quasi-state.” In its first years of existence, the fledgling United States waged war against the Barbary pirate regencies. Buccaneering was their busi­ness, and the corsairs energetically targeted American merchant ships peacefully ferrying pickled fish and wheat across the Mediterranean.

Monday, May 19, 2008

A Little Bit Alt.Country

In the May 9 issue of Entertainment Weekly magazine, horror writer Stephen King lists the 20 songs from his iTunes library that he plays the most often. Alt.country music features heavily, including three artists off the Bloodshot label: "La Cienega Just Smiled," by Ryan Adams, at 16, "CB Song," by Th' Legendary Shack Shakers at number 5, and "Castanets," by Alejandro Escovedo at number 4.

At number 8, he has one my favourite songs of all time, the wonderful "California Stars," a Woody Guthrie song performed by Billy Bragg and Wilco from the album Mermaid Avenue. One of the happiest, most sublime experiences of my life included a late-night performance of this song by Edward Burch and LeRoy Bach in back of The Hideout after a long, sunny day's boozing. You can watch it being performed here.

Saturday, May 17, 2008

Critchley, Zizek, Graeber

Slackbastard has more here and here, including some quality comments.

Thursday, May 15, 2008

Soupy Norman

Nice Bristles

Yes, Bristles. New blogroll link to the funny as fuck and very interesting Bristling Badger.






Check out the link to the Celebrities Guild of Great Britain: "Helping the Handicapped." Please tell me that isn't a genuine organization.

Tuesday, May 13, 2008

Monday, May 12, 2008

Treja Vu

Do you get the feeling this has happened before? Twice?

Business As Usual

An article by Alexander Stille, "Italy: The Crooks in Control," from the April 17 issue of the New York Review of Books on Roberto Saviano's book Gomorrah, about the Camorra.


Saviano gives a telling account of the ways in which organized crime in southern Italy fits into a world system of contraband goods—textiles, appliances, arms, and drugs—with connections to China's huge production of counterfeit goods, to off-the-books (but not necessarily criminal) employment in Italy, arms trafficking in Eastern Europe, construction and real estate in northern Europe, and the drug trade of South America. All of this adds up to an international underground economy that has implications far beyond its local boundaries.

. . .

The region north of Naples and extending throughout much of southern Italy contains clusters of small sweatshop businesses that make high-quality clothes for the leading fashion houses of Italy. At the same time, the very same workshops, in cooperation with camorristi, produce identical clothes bearing counterfeit labels of leading fashion brands—Versace, Armani, Val-entino. These sell throughout the world, often in stores and shopping centers owned by the Camorra. But, Saviano comments,

"The clothes made by the clans aren't the typical counterfeit goods, cheap imitations, or copies passed off as the real thing, but rather a sort of false-true. All that's missing is the final step: the brand name, the official authorization of the motherhouse. But the clans usurp that authorization without asking anybody's permission.... The Secondigliano clans [connected to the town of Secondigliano] have acquired entire retail chains, thus spreading their commercial network across the globe and dominating the international clothing market. They also provide distribution to outlet stores. Products of slightly inferior quality have yet another venue: African street vendors and market stalls. Nothing goes unused."


This form of capitalism suits a world in which retailers are competing ferociously to squeeze every last dollar of profit from each product and consumers look for every penny of savings; almost no one has any reason to question or complain about these well-made products of dubious origin. Despite the violation of their trademarks, the big fashion houses have been surprisingly slow to protest. Saviano suggests shrewdly that copying the brand may have actually served the interests of the big-name clothing makers. A new class of middle-income consumers may go on to buy the real thing:

"The garments they turned out were not inferior and didn't disgrace the brands' quality or design image. Not only did the clans not create any symbolic competition with the designer labels, they actually helped promote products whose market price made them prohibitive to the general public. In short, the clans were promoting the brand."

The camorristi have allowed ordinary citizens to "invest" their savings in drug shipments, a poor man's stock market in which an elderly pensioner might double her income in a month. And they have found a new way to run extortion rackets. Rather than holding up shopkeepers for their monthly pizzo, they started "taxing" wholesale suppliers and taking over the distribution of goods. Many clan members became the chief representatives of major food suppliers in the Naples area. The system has had advantages for the supply companies. Companies that submitted to the clan system, Saviano writes, "experienced a 40 to 80 percent increase in annual sales."

Of course, the suppliers get the market advantage of a virtual monopoly for their products. Recent investigations have shown that the Camorra had a hand in two of Italy's major financial scandals of recent years, the failure of the food conglomerates Parmalat and Cirio. In both cases, Camorra groups handled the distri-bution for both companies not only in Campania but in other regions as well.

While stressing the great market efficiency of the Camorra, and portraying the clan leaders as resourceful capitalists, Saviano ignores the disastrous economic effects of clan domination for the overall economy of southern Italy. "They've created a kind of Soviet economy," according to Francesco Curcio, a magistrate in Naples who has conducted some of the most important Camorra investigations of recent years. "They are monopolies run by the Camorra. If someone presents a bid for a contract, the Camorra tells them, you make an offer of x and I will make one of x minus one." In one case, Curcio did a study of the milk market in the area near Caserta, a town north of Naples, and discovered that milk cost more there than in Milan. "They strangle the economy by deciding who gets to participate and at what price," he said. "People pay two sets of taxes, one to the state and the other to the Camorra. And naturally, no investors want to come here to Campania."

Friday, May 09, 2008

On Tour

A good friend of C&S, Chris Mills, is touring the UK this month with the added bonus of support from the excellent Liam Dullaghan (The Havenots). Do go to see them if you can; you won't be disappointed.

May 21st >> The Maze >>Nottingham, UK

May 22nd >> 12 Bar Club >>London, UK

May 23rd >> Briton's Protection >>Manchester, UK

May 24th >> The Chattery >>Swansea, UK

May 25th >> The Labour Club >>Northampton, UK

What do you mean, "Metaphor"?

Mancur Olson discusses the origins of the state in Power and Prosperity:



The Criminal Metaphor



Power is exercised by human beings, who are, of course, extraordinarily complex. As I see it, human beings rarely act out of unmixed motives. There is not only self-interest but also a benevolent element—and even a malevolent streak—in human nature. Historical outcomes surely depend not only on the incentives and self-interest of those with power but also on their morals and temperaments. I will, before the end of this book, analyze some contexts where disinterested and principled choices are decisive for progress of societies, but I start with a focus on the incentives and inducements to rational and self-interested action that face those with power.

For our focus on coercive power and our analysis of self-interested behavior, I use a criminal metaphor. Clearly, we cannot understand robbery as either a voluntary trade or a moral act, and thus it helps us to focus only on the self-interested use of coercive power. With the aid of this metaphor, we will be able to see beneath the surface and then construct the needed theory. Since criminal behavior is the exception rather than the rule in a successful society, the criminal metaphor will also remind us of the extent to which we are abstracting from the complexity of human nature.

Consider the incentives facing the individual criminal in a populous society. Other things being equal, a criminal is better off in a rich society than in a poor society: there is more to steal. Theft also makes societies less prosperous than they would otherwise be—the time devoted to theft produces nothing, but it reduces the rewards from productive work and investment and induces a diversion of resources from production into guards, locks, police, prisons, inventory control systems, and the like. Therefore, the crime committed by each criminal reduces the wealth of society and thus also the amount that is available to steal. Does this make the individual criminal curtail his or her crime?

Everyone already knows that it does not, but we must understand why. The typical individual thief in a society of, say, a million people, bears about one-millionth of the loss to society that occurs because his crime makes society’s output less than it would otherwise be. Yet he alone normally bears the whole loss of whatever opportunities for theft he passes up. Therefore, the gain to criminals from a wealthier society and the reduction in that society’s wealth due to crime do not keep crime from paying. (The opposite would be true only in a bizarre case where the loss to society from a theft were about a million times or more as valuable as what was taken by theft.) It is only society’s punishment of criminals that keeps crime from paying, and it is not always sufficient to inflict punishment. Though each criminal has a stake in the prosperity of society, that stake is so minuscule that the criminal ignores it: he normally takes everything there is in any purse or till. As we shall see, it makes a huge difference whether individuals with coercive capacities have a minuscule or narrow stake in the society, on the one hand, or an encompassing interest, on the other.

Before turning to encompassing interests, we must remind ourselves that the same self-interest that made the criminal steal leads to dramatically different results when there is voluntary exchange in the market. If, say, better deterrence of crime led our criminal to serve his interests through voluntary exchange in the labor market, he would typically take the job that offered the highest pay. No profit-maximizing employer employs a worker who does not add at least as much to the firm’s revenues as that worker costs. In self-interestedly seeking the highest wage, our ex-criminal works at jobs where his marginal social productivity or contribution to output tends to be greatest.

Now let us contrast the individual criminal in a populous community with the head of a Mafia family or other criminal gang that can monopolize crime in a neighborhood. Suppose that in some well-defined turf, a criminal gang cannot only steal more or less as it pleases but can prevent anyone else from committing crime there. Obviously, the Mafia family has an incentive to keep other thieves out of its own domain. But will it gain from taking all that it can on its own ground? Definitely not.

If business in this domain is made unprofitable by theft, or migration away from the neighborhood is prompted by crime, then the neighborhood will not generate as much income and there will not be as much to steal. Indeed, the Mafia family with a true and continuing monopoly on crime in a neighborhood will not commit any robberies at all. If it monopolizes crime in the neighborhood, it will gain from promoting business profitability and safe residential life there. Thus, the secure Mafia family will maximize its take by selling protection—both against the crime it would commit itself (if not paid) as well as that which would be committed by others (if it did not keep out other criminals). Other things being equal, the better the community is as an environment for business and for living, the more the protection racket will bring in. Accordingly, if one Mafia family has the power to monopolize crime, there is little or no crime (apart from the protection racket). The considerable literature on monopolized crime makes it clear that secure monopolization of crime does, in fact, usually lead to protection rackets rather than ordinary crime. Outbreaks of theft and violence in Mafia-type environments are normally a sign that the controlling gang is losing its monopoly.

This criminal metaphor illustrates the theory of narrow and encompassing interests presented in my book The Rise and Decline of Nations. The individual robber in a populous society obtains such a narrow or minute share of any loss or gain to society that he ignores the damage his thievery does to society. By contrast, the Mafia family that monopolizes crime in a community has, because of this monopoly, a moderately encompassing interest or stake in the income of that community, so it takes the interest of the community into account in using its coercive power. Whereas the individual criminal in a populous society bears only a minuscule share of the social loss from his crime, the gang with a secure monopoly on crime in a neighborhood obtains a significant fraction of the total income of the community from its protection tax theft. Because of the encompassing interest in the income of society that this monopoly gives, it bears a significant fraction of social losses, including those from its own protection tax theft. Therefore, though the individual criminal normally takes all of the money in the wallet he steals, the secure and rational Mafia leader never sets a protection tax rate anywhere near 100 percent: this would reduce the neighborhood’s income so much that the Mafia family itself would be a net loser.


The Stationary Bandit

A story about a Chinese warlord suggests that we need to take this logic further. In the 1920s, China was in large part underthe control of various warlords. They were men who led armed bands with which they conquered a territory and then appointed themselves lords of the territories they had conquered. They taxed their subjects heavily and used the proceeds to serve their own interests. The warlord who I was reading about, Feng Yu-hsiang, was noted for the exceptional extent to which he used his army for suppressing thievery and for his defeat of the relatively substantial army of a notorious roving bandit called White Wolf. Apparently, most people in Feng’s domain wanted him to stay as warlord and greatly preferred him to the roving bandits.

At first, this situation was puzzling: Why should warlords who were simply stationary bandits continuously stealing from a given group of victims he preferred, by those victims, to roving bandits who soon departed? The warlords had no claim to legitimacy and their thefts were distinguished from those of roving bandits only because they took the form of relentless tax theft rather than occasional plunder.

There is a good reason for this preference. As we have seen, there is little production in an anarchy and thus not much to steal. If the leader of a roving bandit gang who finds only slim pickings is strong enough to take hold of a given territory and to keep other bandits out, he can monopolize crime in that area—he becomes a stationary bandit. The advantage of this monopoly over crime is not mainly that he can take what others might have stolen: it is rather that it gives him an encompassing interest in the territory akin to that of the Mafia family considered in the previous section. He actually has a stronger encompassing interest than the Mafia family, since the bandit leader who takes over an anarchic area does not have competition from any government’s tax collectors: he is the only one who is able to tax or steal in the domain in question.

This monopoly of theft changes incentives dramatically. We have seen that the individual criminal in a populous society has such a narrow or minuscule interest in the society that he rationally ignores the damage he does to it, which is obviously also true of a gang of bandits passing through. These socially perverse incentives make anarchies work badly. The encompassing interest of a stationary bandit leader who can continue to keep out not only other criminals but outside tax collectors as well gives him an incentive to behave very differently.

First, it leads him to reduce the percentage he takes from each victim of his theft. As we have seen, the criminal who is only one among many will take 100 percent of the money in any till he robs. By contrast, the stationary bandit with continuing control of an area wants to make sure that the victims have a motive to produce and to engage in mutually advantageous trade. The more income the victims of theft generate, the more there is to take. A secure stationary bandit, by making his theft a predictable tax that takes only a part of his victims’ outputs, thereby leaves them with an incentive to generate income. If he cuts his rate of tax theft from 95 percent to 90 percent, he doubles his subjects’ posttax reward for production and trade, which might well increase output and tax receipts by a large multiple.

The stationary bandit keeps on gaining from reducing his rate of tax theft down to the point where what he gains (from tax theft on a larger output) is just offset by what he loses (from taking a smaller share of that output). He is left at the revenue-maximizing rate of tax theft. If the stationary bandit cut his tax rate from 51 percent to 50 percent, thereby raising output of his domain from 98 percent to 100 percent, he would essentially maximize his tax collections: he would receive half of the increase in output, which would be approximately offset by the reduction in his share of total output. That is, the stationary bandit, because of his monopoly on crime and taxation, has an encompassing interest in his domain that makes him limit his predations because he bears a substantial share of the social losses resulting from these predations. If the stationary bandit in the example above increases his tax rate from 50 percent, he bears about half of the social or “deadweight” loss from the distortion of incentives that this higher rate of predation brings about, which is enough to keep him from taking more. Generally speaking, the greater the loss in production from taxation at any given rate of tax, the lower the rate of tax theft at which the stationary bandit’s take is maximized. Though the deadweight losses and how they vary with tax rates—and thus a stationary bandit’s rate of tax vary from case to case—every stationary bandit has a rate of tax theft that is always lower than 100 percent—and usually much lower—which maximizes his collections.


A Benefactor to Those He Robs

The second way in which the encompassing interest of the stationary bandit changes his incentives is that it gives him an incentive to provide public goods that benefit his domain and those from whom his tax theft is taken. Paradoxically, he provides these public goods with money that he fully controls and could spend entirely on himself. We know that a public good benefits everyone in some area or group and that many public goods, such as levees that protect against floods, police that deter crime, and quarantines that limit contagious diseases, make a society more productive.

Because the stationary bandit obtains a known share of any increase in the output of his domain, given by his optimal rate of tax theft,9 he has an incentive to spend his resources on all productivity-enhancing public goods up to the point where his last dollar spent on these goods equals his share of the resulting increase in output.’° Thus, if the stationary bandit’s optimal rate of tax theft is 50 percent, he will spend on public goods up to the point where the last dollar spent on these goods adds $2 to the output of the domain, since he will then receive $1. More generally, if the stationary bandit’s share of any increase in output is S, he will best serve his interests by spending the resources he controls on public goods up to the point where the output of the domain increases by 1/S. Readers who want formal proofs and a mathematical and geometric exposition of this argument should consult an article by Martin McGuire and myself on “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule.”


The Origin of Autocracy

In short, the bandit leader, if he is strong enough to hold a territory securely and monopolize theft there, has an encompassing interest in his domain. This encompassing interest leads him to limit and regularize the rate of his theft and to spend some of the resources that he controls on public goods that benefit his victims no less than himself. Since the settled bandit’s victims are for him a source of tax payments, he prohibits the murder or maiming of his subjects. Because stealing by his subjects, and the theft-averting behavior that it generates, reduces total income, the bandit does not allow theft by anyone but himself. He serves his interests by spending some of the resources that he controls to deter crime among his subjects and to provide other public goods. A bandit leader with sufficient strength to control and hold a territory has an incentive to settle down, to wear a crown, and to become a public good–providing autocrat.

Thus, governments for large groups of people have normally arisen because of the rational self-interest of those who can organize the greatest capacity for violence. These violent entrepreneurs naturally do not call themselves bandits, but on the contrary give themselves and their descendants exalted titles. They sometimes even claim to rule by divine right. Since history is written by the winners, the origins of ruling dynasties are, of course, conventionally explained in terms of lofty motives rather than by self-interest. Autocrats of all kinds usually claim that their subjects want them to rule and thereby nourish the usually false assumption that their governments arose out of some kind of voluntary choice.

Once we understand how the incentives of a bandit gang change when it can settle down and securely hold a territory, we see why the warlord’s subjects, even though he extracts tax theft from them year after year, prefer him to the roving bandits who rob only sporadically. Roving banditry means anarchy, and replacing anarchy with government brings about a considerable increase in output. The subjects of a stationary bandit obtain the proportion of the increase in income that is not taken in taxes. The logic of the matter—and historical information and recent observations—suggests that the continuing exactions of a stationary bandit are far better than anarchy.

It follows that the familiar metaphor of the predatory state is inadequate, even for autocracies with utterly selfish leaders. As we saw earlier, a stationary bandit has an encompassing interest in the territory he controls and accordingly provides domestic order and other public goods. Thus, he is not like the wolf that preys on the elk, but more like the rancher who makes sure that his cattle are protected and given water. No metaphor or model of even the autocratic state can therefore be correct unless it takes account of the stationary bandit’s incentive to provide public goods while maximizing his rate of tax theft.

Wednesday, May 07, 2008

Primavera Band Profile 2008 #3

Bon Iver

For Emma Forever Ago (Jagjaguawar, 2008)

A mattress of acoustic guitars and fine percussions is all that needs the Nord American Justin Vernon to follow the track of a bit more chilled Sam Bean and embark on exploring the inner deserts without any other compass than his own intuition. Grown inside the indie folk band DeYarmond Edison, with which recorded Silent Signs, Verno has just made his solo debut with For Emma Forever Ago, crackling heartbreaking emotional altarpiece that searches bellows in the folk and in the disconcerting falsetto with which the Wisconsin artist hypnotizes his songs.

Saturday, May 03, 2008

Here's to Bank Holiday Weekends



When all normal people have fucked off to the beach.




(Irish Blogs: Humour Category. No. 1 is Bock the Robber. McManus is No. 12 although it hasn't been updated for nigh on a year - huge hits for porn, you see. Khmer Rouge Strippergram is No. 13.)

Every Girl Loves a Fascist



Russell Brand's paean to Paolo di Canio in today's Guardian Footie supplement.

"At one point I touched his shoulder with my hand and it was as if it were connected to the Earth's core, such was the throb of innate potency."

Yeah, right. His "shoulder."

Friday, May 02, 2008

It's Friday! Let's Boogie.



Puerto Muerto- The Hangman's Song